THE EFFECT OF DIRECT TO CONSUMER TELEVISION ADVERTISING ON THE TIMING OF TREATMENT
W. DAVID BRADFORD, ANDREW N. KLEIT, PAUL J. NIETERT and STEVEN ORNSTEIN∗
We examine how direct to consumer advertising affects the delay between diagnosisand pharmacological treatment for patients suffering from a common chronic disease. The primary data for this study consist of patients diagnosed with osteoarthritis(N = 18,235) taken from a geographically diverse national research network of 72primary care practices with 348 physicians in 27 states over the 1999–2002 timeperiod. Brand-specific advertising data were collected for local and network televisionat the monthly level for the nearest media markets to the practices. Results of durationmodels of delay to treatment suggest advertising does affect the length of time thatpatients and physicians wait to initiate therapy. This evidence suggests that these effectsmay be welfare enhancing in that advertising tends to encourage more rapid adoptionamong patients who are good clinical candidates for the therapy and leads to lessrapid adoption among some patients who are poor clinical candidates. (JEL D12, I11)
the disease and the drug brand name (as long asa brief list of side effects was mentioned and a
In August 1997, the Food and Drug Adminis-
1–800 number or World Wide Web site was pro-
tration (FDA) relaxed the rules governing tele-
vided with more detailed information). Spend-
vision advertising of prescription pharmaceuti-
ing for direct to consumer advertising (DTCA)
cal products. Before that time, broadcast ads
for prescription drugs went from $985 million
were permitted only to mention either the name
in 1996 to approximately $4.2 billion for 2005
of a drug or a disease against which a drug
(Donohue, Cevasco, and Rosenthal 2007). This
was effective but not both. After August 1997,
has led to a great deal of debate in the med-
pharmaceuticals were allowed to mention both
ical profession and among health care insurersand managed care organizations and an ongo-
*The authors would like to thank Jack Calfee, John Caw-
ley, and Terry Steyer for their comments and assistance on
ing review of advertising rules by the FDA.
this paper as well as participants at the Sloan Program Con-
However, very little is actually known about the
ference on Consumers, Information and the Evolving Health-
effects of DTCA for the efficient allocation of
care Market Place, the 2005 Annual Health Economics Con-
ference (State College, Pennsylvania), and the 2005 Inter-national Health Economics Biannual Congress (Barcelona).
This paper was funded by grants from the Agency for
cian prescribing patterns and courses of care
Healthcare Research and Quality (1 R01 HS011326-01A2)
for patients suffering from a representative
and from the National Heart, Lung and Blood Institute(1 R01 HL077841-01).
chronic condition, osteoarthritis (OA). Thiscondition is of special significance, as one
Bradford: Busbee Chair in Public Policy, 201C Bald-
win Hall, Department of Public Administration and
of the major products in this area, Merck’s
Policy, University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602.
“Vioxx” cyclooxygenase-2 (COX-2) inhibitor,
Phone 706-542-2731, Fax 706-583-0610, E-Mail brad-
was forced to withdraw from the market in
Kleit: Professor of Energy and Environmental Economics,
MICASU Faculty Fellow, Department of Meteorology,Department of Energy and Mineral Engineering, Penn-sylvania State University, 507 Walker Building, Univer-
ABBREVIATIONS Nietert: Associate Professor, Department of Medicine, Med-
ical University of South Carolina, 135 Cannon St., Room
403J, Charleston, SC 29425. Phone (843) 876-1204,
Ornstein: Professor, Department of Family Medicine, Medi-
cal University of South Carolina, Charleston, SC 29425. Phone (843) 876-1213, E-mail ornstesm@musc.edu
Online Early publication September 24, 2009
2009 Western Economic Association International
October 2004 due to side effects on patients
pharmaceutical, making it the 39th most adver-
with heart conditions. The side effects of Vioxx
tised brand of any kind in 2000 (“Top brands
have caused considerable criticism of Merck’s
in network primetime –2000” 2001). Over the
advertising strategy for Vioxx (see, e.g., editori-
same time periods, Pharmacia and Pfizer jointly
als from the New England Journal of Medicine;
spent $78 million in DTCA supporting Cele-
The primary goal of this paper was to deter-
DTCA in the context of the market for COX-
mine what effect local and national television
2 inhibitors. During the period spanned by our
advertising on behalf of the two main COX-2
data (1999–2002), the two available COX-2
inhibitors had on the treatment decisions that
inhibitors were Vioxx and Celebrex. These drugs
patients made in collaboration with their physi-
are appropriate subjects of study for a number
cians. In particular, we will examine the impact
of reasons. First, they have been heavily adver-
of DTCA on the time patients wait after diag-
tised. Second, they are significantly more expen-
nosis with OA and before initiating treatment
sive than alternative pharmacologic treatments
with a COX-2 inhibitor. The paper will pro-
for chronic pain. Third, data published approxi-
ceed by first reviewing the literature on DTCA
mately halfway through our sample period indi-
in Section II. Section III will present a the-
cated that these products may carry a signifi-
oretical model of optimal delay to treatment.
cant risk of adverse cardiac side effects. Conse-
Section IV will present details of the data
quently, from mid-2001, many physicians began
and empirical model we implement. Empiri-
to question the wisdom in their use (Topol
cal results are presented in Section V, and
2004). Additionally, given the widespread sus-
Section VI concludes with a discussion about
picion of advertising for prescription drugs,
clinicians and policy makers have questionedwhether DTCA for COX-2’s might be caus-ing fatalities. Our results will speak directly tothis issue in that if DTCA had a deleterious
effect (in terms of matching high-risk patientsto COX-2 use) then we will get one sign pat-
A. Advertising for COX-2 Inhibitors
tern on interaction terms between advertising
Historically, pharmaceutical advertising was
and patient comorbidities. If, however, DTCA
done largely through “detailing” —promotion
is having a positive effect (by matching patients
directly from the manufacturer to the physician,
most suited for COX-2 inhibitors with that ther-
either through visits by representatives or con-
apy) then we will get the opposite sign pat-
tacts by pharmacists or through advertisements
tern on the advertising-comorbidity interaction
in professional journals. Since the mid-1980s,
however, drug companies in the United States
have increasingly turned their marketing strate-
television advertising for both Celebrex and
gies directly toward the consumer. This advertis-
Vioxx at the national (network) level and for
ing largely takes place through television media
the top 75 local media markets in the United
and in newspapers. This change in advertis-
States. These data are aggregated to the monthly
ing approach has its share of both critics and
level. Celebrex was approved by the FDA in
The pharmaceutical industry in the United
May 1999. Thus, at least one of the products
States is large —accounting for more than $132
was available for use over the entire 1999–2002
billion in retail sales in 2000 alone (NIHCM
time period of our analysis. Figure 1 presents the
2001). In 2000, Celebrex (celecoxib), the lead-
2000–2002 trend for the spending on national
ing COX-2 inhibitor, had sales of approxi-
television advertising for Vioxx and Celebrex
mately $2.6 billion (“Pharmacia has setback
taken from our advertising database (described
for parecoxib” 2001)—while Vioxx (rofecoxib)
sold more than $1.2 billion in the first half of2000 (Knight Ridder News 2001). In supportof Vioxx, Merck spent almost $161 million in
B. Literature on the Impact of DTCA
In economic terms, we would expect adver-
the most spent on DTCA for any prescription
tising for prescription drugs to have three
National Celebrex and Vioxx Advertising Dollars
2000.012000.032000.052000.072000.092000.112001.012001.032001.052001.072001.092001.112002.012002.032002.052002 2002.092002.11
possible effects. First, advertisement for a par-
been published to date have yielded conflict-
ticular prescription product will provide infor-
ing results. There is an arm of this literature
mation regarding the symptoms and regarding
that is generally supportive of advertising in
the fact that effective treatments are available
this market, such as work by Telser (1975) and
about the medical condition that the drug treats.
Leffler (1981). Keith (1995) finds that patient
This may be labeled a “public good” effect,
suggestions regarding pharmaceuticals (aspirin
as the information conveyed by advertisements
for cardiovascular disease) are important deter-
for one brand may aid sales of all brands sell-
minants in prescription decisions and that adver-
ing competing products. Second, advertisements
tising tends to lead to more appropriate care as
may provide important information regarding
a consequence. In this, Keith is advancing an
side effects, contraindications, and the like that
argument made earlier by Masson and Rubin
may prompt patients to consult with their physi-
that posits several mechanisms that could leadto positive impacts from advertising on the effi-
cian regarding a treatment modality. This com-
ciency of the pharmaceutical market (includ-
ponent of the advertising may be labeled as a
ing that it might encourage people to associate
“matching” effect since it would assist patients
symptoms with a disease and seek care or that it
and physicians in matching treatment regimes.
might alert people to treatments they were previ-
Third, advertising may simply lead patients to
ously unaware of, which would encourage them
demand a product because of the aesthetic or
to seek care) (Masson and Rubin 1985). For a
persuasive characteristics of the ad, or the rep-
survey of the more optimistic literature in this
utational impact of the ad, rather than the effi-
area, see Rubin (1991) and Kleit (1998).
cacy of the drug. This effect may be labeled
as a “brand” effect. Since health care markets,
guine about the prospects of positive wel-
including pharmaceuticals, are often character-
fare effects from prescription pharmaceutical
ized by moral hazard (as patients do not gen-
advertising. Hurwitz and Caves (1988) find
erally pay the full cost of the medications they
that—on net—promotional activities by phar-
consume), the welfare implications of this third
maceutical firms tend to have the effect of
preserving market share for existing products
The studies on the impact of advertising in
the prescription pharmaceutical market that have
pounds in the market. King (1996) uses monthly
sales data in the ulcer drug market to test
to initiate treatment, the patient will evaluate
the effect that marketing efforts have on the
her utility with treatment and her utility without
industry. He finds that marketing by a firm
treatment and pick whichever path yields the
causes the demand for the firm’s own prod-
highest expected value. If the instantaneous
ucts to become more inelastic. Similarly, Rizzo
utility associated with therapy is not higher
(1999) finds that DTCA significantly reduces
than the utility associated with no therapy then
price elasticity in the market. A reduction in
the patient will choose to delay. Each period
price elasticity would increase opportunities for
thereafter, the patient will undertake the same
utility calculus, to determine whether to begin
The post-1997 era has presented an opportu-
nity for examination of the new policy regime
This model is similar in form to real option
for DTCA, and much of the literature has been
theories that have been applied to financial
focused on the FDA policy shift. As Zachry and
instruments (see, e.g., McDonald and Siegel
Ginsburg point out, however, there is a paucity
1986; Merton 1973), to the timing of land
of studies that examine the actual impacts of
development (see, e.g., Arnott and Lewis 1979;
Capozza and Li 1994, 2002; Titman 1985), and
In one of the few such studies, Dubois (2003)
even to the timing of initial public offerings (see,
examines the impact of DTCA through the lens
e.g., Benninga, Helmantel, and Sarig 2005). An
of variation in procedure and drug use. He notes
interior optimum for the delay to an action can
previous evidence that there is a wide geo-
exist when there is a cost to undertaking some
graphic variety in the use of various medications
action and when the benefits from the action
and suggests that such variations imply under-
served populations. Dubois cites several sources
We will motivate our empirical research by
that indicate that geographic variations in pre-
exploring a simple model of the timing of treat-
scriptions have declined since the relaxation
ment for a stylized chronic disease. Consider
of DTCA regulations, perhaps implying that
a patient who has been diagnosed with a con-
DTCA is conveying important medication infor-
dition, which reduces her health. Furthermore,
mation to previously underserved populations.
assume that the impact on health is cumula-
Calfee, Winston, and Stempski (2002) study
tive —delaying treatment implies that the health
whether the August 1997 policy changes at FDA
state continues to decay. The progression of
increased the demand for the statin class of
the disease can be countered by pharmacolog-
drugs using monthly data from IMSHealth and
ical therapy. (Assume for the sake of simplic-
Scott-Levin for a 58-mo period. The authors,
ity that there is only one viable therapeutic
however, found that advertising did not have a
option.) The value of that therapy is unknown,
statistically significant impact on aggregate pre-
but the patient has expectations about the treat-
scriptions filled. According to the authors, “it
ment effect—expectations that can be affected
may only be possible to detect the effect of
by information, such as physician advice, tes-
timonials from friends, or DTCA. Thus, the
disaggregated data that link a patient’s choles-
terol treatment history with the timing of DTCAexpenditures.”
ht = H − δt, if no treatment
H − δt + θ(a), with treatment,
where H is the base level of health at diseaseonset, δ is the impact of the disease on health
during each time period, t represents time, and
Consider a patient who has been diagnosed
θ(.) is the expectations around the pharmaco-
with some chronic disease. On diagnosis, the
logic treatment effect, which can be affected
patient faces a choice —either initiate or delay
by advertising, a. Furthermore, θa > 0 and
treatment. The benefits of treatment are potential
improvements in symptoms of the underlying
Utility is defined across consumption of some
disease. The costs are monetary (the treatment
numeraire good, xt , and health, ht . Consumers
generally must be purchased at some positive
may consume 1 unit of pharmaceutical treatment
market price) and potentially psychic (people
per period, at price P, or may continue to
often resist taking medication) as well as the cost
delay therapy. Once a person chooses to initiate
of any potential side effects. To decide whether
therapy, she will continue to receive treatment
until her death at time T. (Given the degenerative
Since diminishing returns in health imply that
nature of the disease assumed in this model,
the higher levels of health resulting from treat-
once it becomes optimal to purchase treatment, it
ment reduce the marginal utility of health, and
will necessarily be optimal in every time period
the complementarity between income and health
will imply further reductions in Uh with the
Consequently, each patient will maximize the
lower net income resulting from the requirement
present value of lifetime utility by selecting the
that some portion of any consumed therapy is
optimal delay for treatment onset according to:
Comparative static analysis of the impact of
advertising on the optimally selected delay of
U (I, H − δt)e−rt dt
treatment is straightforward. Inserting the opti-mal delay time functional, d∗(.) into Equa-
tion (2) and differentiating with respect to
the advertising parameter, a, and rearranging
+ U(I, H −δt +θ(a))e−rtdt,
where U (.) is patient utility defined across
≡ ∂V 2 · ∂d∗(.) − Uhθa
income (I ) and health. The optimal delay toonset, d∗, is defined by taking the first partial
⇒ ∂d∗(.) = Uhθa < 0.
of Equation (1) with respect to d and setting it
The sign of this effect depends on the sign
d = U (I , H − δd)a . If a patient believes himself to be a good
candidate for the treatment then greater expo-
−U(I − P, H − δd + θ(a)) = 0.
sure to advertising, or other positive informa-tion about the efficacy of the treatment, will
The usual convexity assumptions require that
reduce the optimally chosen delay to therapy
the second partial of Equation (1) with respect
initiation. However, if the advertising conveys
information that leads the patient to believe thathe is a poor candidate for the treatment—by
emphasizing adverse events or highlighting a
≡ Vdd = −δUh(I, H − δd)
contraindication from which the patient suf-
fers —then the expected treatment effect will
h(I − P , H − δd + θ(a)) < 0.
be reduced, which will lengthen the optimal
Given these assumptions, the optimal time to
delay. Thus, whether the information contained
treatment exists, d∗ = d∗(I, H, δ, r, a). Note, of
in the ad is “positive” or “negative” will depend
course, that one condition for an interior solu-
on patient expectations, other diagnoses, and
tion is that at time = 0, the value of utility
preferences across the characteristics of the
without therapy must be greater than the value
of utility with therapy. That is, if U (I − P ,
There are several implications from the theo-
H − δt + θ(a)) > U (I, H − δt)∀t
retical model for the empirical estimation. First,
patient will choose to initiate therapy immedi-
patients select the optimal delay from diagnosis
ately and d∗ = 0. Similarly, if U (I −P , H −
to therapy. Thus, we will calculate below this
δt + θ(a)) < U(I, H − δt)∀t then the patient
delay for each person in the data by estimat-
ing a parametric duration model. Second, since
pharmacological treatments are better suited tosome patients than others, the optimal delay
∂U (I, H − δd) = −δ
will be a function of the patient’s other clin-
ical diagnoses. Finally, the model implies thatthis optimal delay will be a function of income,
−δUh|with T x = ∂U(I − P, H − δd + θ(a)).
health state, opportunity cost of treatment, and
advertising exposure —measured at the point of
therapy initiation. We will employ either direct
Survival Curves for Delay between Diagnosis with OA and Initiating Treatment,
Survival Curves for Delay between Diagnosis with OA and Initiating Treatment,
measures or proxy measures for each of these
nonuse) having persisted to time t. One com-
mon specification for this hazard rate is toassume it is the product of some baseline pop-ulation average hazard and an individual spe-cific term (which may or may not depend on
The problem with this proportional hazard
model is that it requires the population aver-
Before specifying an empirical implementa-
age effect to be constant over time. A more
tion, we note that the decision we will model
flexible approach for duration models is pre-
is one that is joint between the patient and
sented in Kalbfleisch and Prentice (1981) and
the physician. Thus, our question will be “whatimpact does DTCA have on the likelihood that
in Ridder (1990) and known as accelerated fail-
the physician/patient interaction will result in a
ure time (AFT) models. These models permit the
prescription?” We will model the length of the
baseline hazard to increase, decrease, or remain
spell between diagnosis and initiation of COX-2
constant over time. Figure 2 below presents the
inhibitor therapy. There is a long econometric
empirical hazards for the delay to treatment
literature on duration modeling, which presents
data we explore. The instantaneous failure rates
us with various modeling options. Options range
are not constant for our data, as the propor-
from nonparametric methods that impose few
tional hazard assumption is strongly rejected
distributional restrictions to parametric meth-
for nearly all covariates in our models. Con-
ods where the distribution of the “time to fail-
sequently, we will estimate an AFT version of
ure” (to use the language of much of the lit-
a duration model. In addition, the decreasing
erature) must be explicitly specified. All ver-
hazard we observe is consistent with a Weibull
sions of the model are based on estimating the
distribution—which is the distribution we will
hazard function or the likelihood of a transi-
tion (in our case, between nonuse of COX-2
In addition to nonconstancy in the baseline
inhibitors and use of COX-2 inhibitors) between
hazard, we have one other characteristic of
the data to accommodate in our model choice.
Patients may exit their delay spell in one of
agnostic with regard to what the actual mech-
two ways: by choosing Vioxx as the treatment
to initiate or by choosing Celebrex. These exit
ever, to assess whether such selection issues
strategies are not likely to be random and may
are driving the results, we reestimated, ex-post,
consequently affect the length of time that the
both versions of the model presented below
delay spell itself lasts. Thus, we are faced with
and included proxy variables for the probabil-
the possibility of underling heterogeneity in the
ity that the patient seeks a visit and the prob-
duration data, which arises due to unobservable
ability that the patient receives a prescription
characteristics of the patient. Competing risk
during the month when therapy is initiated.
versions of the AFT model can account for
These proxy variables are the percent of all
this data-generating process. For applications of
the physician’s monthly office visits that are to
the competing risk models in health care, see
OA patients and the percent of all the physi-
Hamilton (1997), Cutler (1995), and Picone,
cian’s monthly visits to OA patients that are
Wilson, and Chou (2003). These models are
associated with a COX-2 inhibitor prescription,
based on the generalized method of Heckman
respectively. These variables represent na¨ıve
and Singer (1984), which model heterogeneous
estimates of the probability of a visit and pre-
transition frailty as a multiplicative term with a
scription for each patient during the month in
which the patient actually began therapy. Since
Thus, we will model the delay to COX-2 ini-
these are practice average measures, they will
tiation as an AFT hazard function with heteroge-
be exogenous to the individual patient’s char-
neous failures in a competing risk model where
acteristics but capture general influences at the
the instantaneous hazard follows a Weibull dis-
practice level on the likelihood that the patient
tribution, and the unobservable heterogeneity is
progresses to treatment. The estimated DTCA
modeled as a gamma distribution. The hazard
parameters and the parameters on the DTCA
interaction effects were highly robust to inclu-sion or exclusion of these variables —thus sug-gesting that selection effects are not playing alarge role in generating the results we present
λi(t, xi, β, σi, αj) = exiβαjtαj−1α ,
below. For the sake of simplicity, therefore, we
do not include these models in Table 3; how-ever, they are available on request from the
characteristics, t is the duration of the individualdelay spell, and αj capture the group-levelheterogeneity in exit (to Vioxx or Celebrex). For
some patients, it will be optimal to delay longer
than we observe them, and for some, it will be
television advertising for both Celebrex and
optimal to delay indefinitely. Given that we only
Vioxx at the national (network) level and for
have data spanning the 1999–2002 time period,
the top 75 local media markets in the United
these two populations will be observationally
States. These data are aggregated to the monthly
equivalent—requiring that we take right-hand
level. Figure 1 presents the 2000–2002 trend
censoring into account. The model is estimated
for the dollars spent on national television
advertising for Vioxx and Celebrex taken from
Finally, one remaining issue to be addressed
is whether any selection effects are at work
As Figure 1 indicates, at the national level,
in the models. It seems plausible that advertis-
monthly advertising exposure for the two brands
ing could bring more people to the physician
is roughly comparable over the entire 2000–
office —which is what we find in prior research
2002 time period. Interestingly, a very differ-
(Bradford et al. 2006). While this may lead
ent picture emerges at the local level, where
to more diagnoses of OA, it is not immedi-
television advertising spots for Celebrex are
ately clear that this would bias our estimates
always greater than that of Vioxx for the entire
on how long individuals wait before adopting
period. The value of ads purchased at the local
therapy. (Even if the shift in patient popula-
level is much lower in dollar terms than at
tion did lead to a change in delay, our esti-
the national level. Since patients do not gen-
mates are reduced form in nature and thus
erally distinguish between the payment source
of a television ad (whether the local station
or national network receives the revenue), we
will include measures of the total spending on
tices indicates that the patient population is
television advertising in our empirical mod-
approximately 57% female, with a mean age
els. Consequently, we will have both cross-
(±SD) of 43.1 ± 21.1 yr and has a racial break-
sectional and across time variation in DTCA
African American, and 4.3% Hispanic. PPR-Net practices are located in urban, suburban,and rural areas. Based on a four-tiered classi-
fication scheme for the Rural-Urban Commut-
Practice Partner, Inc. (Seattle, Washington)
ing Area codes (Morrill, Cromartie, and Hart
has marketed a commercial electronic medi-
1999), PPRNet practices are highly represen-
cal record (i.e., Practice Partner) to physician
tative of the distribution of the U.S. popula-
practices for more than a decade. This prod-
tion. Among the 114 practices active as of
uct is intended to replace paper charts and
December 2005, there are 462 physicians, 51
has been widely adopted—largely by prac-
physician assistants, and 63 nurse practitioners.
tices that are community based—for clinical
Eighty-nine (78%) are family medicine prac-
reasons and not for research purposes (nor
tices; four of these are family medicine res-
because the practice has any affiliation with
idency programs. Twenty (18%) are internal
a research group or institution). The Medi-
medicine practices and five (4%) are combined
cal University of South Carolina collaborates
practices of primary care physicians. Thus, the
with the vendor to gain access to the record
PPRNet practices appear reasonably representa-
extracts of practices that were willing to have
tive of other primary care practices in the United
their data used for research purposes. This
led to the development of a geographicallydiverse national research network of ambula-tory, mostly primary care practices that use thissingle electronic medical record system (known
as PPRNet). We will examine data on prac-tices from 1999 through 2002. As of 2002
(the end of the study period), 72 practices in
the length of time each patient waits before
25 states, with 348 physicians, were network
initiating therapy with one of the two COX-
2 inhibitors after being diagnosed with OA.
Each quarter, participating practices run a
This is calculated as the difference (in days)
computer program, developed and maintained
between the diagnosis date for OA (recorded
by the electronic medical record vendor, to
in the clinical data) and the prescribing date
extract patient activity of the previous quar-
for the first instance of a Vioxx or Celebrex
ter from the electronic medical record system.
prescription. However, COX-2 inhibitors are
These data are taken from the patient’s med-
used for many complaints in addition to OA;
ical record—similar to chart abstraction. The
additionally, patients may use a COX-2 for
data capture all diagnoses, medications, patient
occasional arthritis pain even before a formal
characteristics (weight, blood pressure, etc.), lab
diagnosis is made. In these cases, the “delay”
tests ordered, and lab results. Currently, theentire research network database has informa-
would be negative. For such negative delays,
tion on 604,111 patients, including 3.6 mil-
the duration between the diagnosis and the
lion patient contacts, 3.8 million prescription
prescription is set to 1 d. In addition, most of the
records, 10.1 million vital signs, 12 million lab-
patients with a diagnosis of OA do not receive
oratory records, and 1.3 million preventive ser-
a prescription for Vioxx or Celebrex as long as
vices records. We extract a subset of this data
they are observed in the data. Thus, the duration
on 22,011 patients who had ever been diag-
models we estimate will control for this right
nosed with OA and who had physician visits
in the years 1999–2002. (The time period of
analysis is dictated by the availability of adver-
eral categories, such as advertising information,
tising data and not the availability of clinical
patient individual clinical information, and mar-
We obtained national and local advertising
patient is female. We also include variables
information from Competitive Media Report-
that capture whether the patient has ever been
ing, Inc., which collects data on media adver-
diagnosed with (or treated for) other relevant
tising for all products, including pharmaceuti-
comorbidities. These include indicator variables
cals, at the market (e.g., city) level. The data
for if the patient has ever been diagnosed with
are specific to the brand name of the prod-
heart disease (coronary disease or hyperten-
uct. Consequently, it is possible to determine
sion), depression, diabetes, hyperlipidemia, or
which products were advertised, which month
ever treated for gastrointestinal difficulties with
they were advertised, how many times they
proton-pump inhibitors, H2 blockers, or related
were advertised, and how many dollars were
spent on the ads. Patients and physician prac-
Imputations of additional descriptive vari-
tices were assigned to the nearest media mar-
kets separately by two of the authors. When
imputed the price of an intermediate length
a practice was close to multiple media mar-
of physician’s office visit with an established
kets, they were assigned to the one that was
patient from the American Chamber of Com-
nearest (by driving miles). In addition, we
merce Research Association’s Quarterly Price
excluded all practices that are unusually far
Reports (http://www.coli.org/). These quarterly
from the nearest media market (more than 100
reports contain average prices for 50 commodi-
straight-line miles) to avoid any bias from mis-
ties (including physician office visits) for around
matching of practice and local media market
300 metropolitan areas. The linking between
average physician visit price and the patient
We measure advertising exposure as the total
was accomplished by using the average price
(national and local) dollars spent on ads broad-
in the metropolitan area nearest the primary
cast for each brand advertised. We add the
care practice site. Average county per capita
separate measures for national advertising and
income, the percent of the county population
local advertising into a single total monthly
covered by Medicare, the percent of the county
spending variable. While it is the case that
employed in the labor force, the percent of
local ads tend to be shown during different
the county population that is Caucasian and
times of the day and during different program-
African American, the county population, and
ming, it is unclear that this difference mat-
the number of physicians per 10,000 popu-
ters empirically. We have estimated versions
lation were also merged onto the data from
of our models with the national and localad spending included separately, and the net
the Area Resource File. Counties were iden-
results are not meaningfully different. Addi-
tified as the county in which the practice is
tionally, the parameters on national advertis-
located. This information is available on an
ing are essentially unchanged in magnitude
and significance if we exclude local advertis-
In addition to the impact of advertising,
ing; so, while there may some concern that
another source of information that may affect
local advertising could be endogenous (a con-
physician prescribing is medical journals. The
cern that is ameliorated by the use of individ-
late 1990s and early 2000s was a period when
ual data, typically from only one practice in
a significant amount of research was being con-
each media market), the practical biases appear
ducted on the efficacy and side effects of COX-2
inhibitors. We will control for clinical knowl-
Additionally, since the theoretical model sug-
edge in two ways. First, over the period of
gests that patient characteristics at the time of
our study (1999–2002), there were more than
the switch are the important factors in initiating
900 publications in English-language medical
therapy, and since we have not captured pre-
journals about COX-2 inhibitors. Of those, 132
cisely when in the month therapy begins, we
were specifically in the area of OA. To con-
will measure potential advertising exposure as
trol for the effect of this research on clinical
the dollars spent in the month preceding the ini-
providers, we created a data series, that mea-
sures the number of publications in each month
The patient data contain limited demographic
that had the keywords: rofecoxib, celecoxib,
and detailed clinical information. For patient
Vioxx, Celebrex, and osteoarthritis. We further
demographic information, we include patient
refined the measure by dividing it into three
age and an indicator variable for whether the
series: the number of publications each month
that focused on Celebrex, the number of publica-
for Celebrex (Vioxx) in the separate models
tions each month that focused on Vioxx, and the
we run for delay to initiation for each brand
number of publications each month that focused
says little about the social welfare impact
sen, and Topol (2001) published an influen-
of DTCA. We can, however, learn something
tial article in a major medical journal where
about the welfare effects of advertising by
they reviewed data available from a major
examining its effect on delay to treatment for
clinical trial, which indicated serious statisti-
patients that are likely to benefit from, or be
cally significant concerns about the cardiovas-
poor candidates for, COX-2 inhibitor use. In
cular risk associated with Vioxx (rofecoxib).
particular, patients who have required treat-
To a lesser, and not statistically significant,
ment for gastrointestinal problems using proton-
extent, the paper raised concerns about Cele-
pump inhibitors, H2 blockers, or other simi-
brex (celecoxib). This was the first publica-
lar treatments are more likely to suffer gastric
tion in a major outlet to raise issues about
irritation from nonsteriodal anti-inflammatory
increased risk of myocardial infarction associ-
drugs (NSAIDs) and so are the good candi-
ated with COX-2 inhibitors in general and Vioxx
dates for COX-2 inhibitors. In this case, we
in particular. These concerns were later to be
identified patients with gastrointestinal comor-
bidities as those who have ever had a pre-
the market in October 2004. We will include
scription for ranitidine (e.g., Zantac), famoti-
an indicator variable, which equals 1 after
dine (e.g., Pepcid), cimetidine (e.g., Tagamet),
August 2001 and 0 otherwise to test whether
omeprazole (e.g., Prilosec), esomeprazole (e.g.,
the practicing clinical community responded
Nexium), lansoprazole (e.g., Previcid), rabepra-
zole (e.g., Aciphex), pantoprazole (e.g., Pro-
of significant DTCA in favor of Vioxx and
tonix), sulcralfate (e.g., Carafate), misoprostol
(e.g., Cytotec), and Helidac, Prevpac, or meto-clopromide (e.g., Reglan). We interacted theadvertising measures with the indicator vari-
E. Possible Impacts of Advertising
able for gastrointestinal problems. If advertis-
There are several variables that are cen-
ing improves patient matching then the param-
tral to understanding the impact of advertising
eters on those interactions will be negative
on patient treatment delay decisions. The first
and significant—indicating shorter delays to
set, obviously, are the measures of advertis-
ing spending on behalf of Vioxx and Celebrex.
In contrast, there are a number of conditions
In general, one would expect the impact of
that make a person a poor candidate for use
Vioxx or Celebrex brand television DTCA to
of a COX-2 inhibitor. These include a diag-
shorten the time that patients wait before initi-
nosis of heart disease (hypertension and other
ating any COX-2 inhibitor treatment—in which
coronary diseases). Individuals with these con-
case the parameter on the advertising measures
ditions should initiate therapy with a COX-2
will be negative and significant. It is possible
inhibitor less frequently, which translates into
that the only effect of advertising is class level.
longer delay times. However, this set of con-
That is, it may not matter which drug is adver-
traindications was not widely discussed in the
tised—any advertising for a COX-2 inhibitor
clinical community until the publication of the
may affect the demand for both approximately
Mukherjee, Nissen, and Topol (MNT) article in
equally. To evaluate this, we will estimate two
August 2001. Consequently, we will test for
versions of the model. The first will include total
the informational components of the DTCA for
dollars spent (as both a linear and a squared
heart disease by including a three-way interac-
term) in the previous month on both Celebrex
tion term between the advertising measures, the
and Vioxx as one variable. The second will
heart disease indicator variable, and the indi-
include separate measures (again, both linear
cator variable for whether the treatment began
and squared terms) for Celebrex and Vioxx ad
after August 2001. If the advertising is con-
spending. If television advertising has a pure
veying clinically useful information then the
class effect then advertisement for Vioxx and
parameter on this interaction will be positive
Celebrex would have roughly equal effects when
and significant (indicating that advertisement
entered individually on the delay to therapy
induces individuals with those comorbidities to
Data Description (N = 18, 235)Standard Variable Deviation
Average delay between diagnosis with OA and first use of COX-2 inhibitor (for 6,494
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising squared, month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising squared, month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising, month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising squared, month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising, month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising squared, month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Patient has received gastrointestinal treatment
Patient has been diagnosed with heart disease
Interaction between gastrointestinal treatment and total COX-2 inhibitor advertising
Interaction between heart disease and total COX-2 inhibitor advertising dollars during
Interaction between heart disease and total COX-2 inhibitor and advertising dollars
Number of journal publications discussing COX-2 inhibitors in month preceding
Number of journal publications discussing Vioxx in month preceding therapy
Number of journal publications discussing Celebrex in month preceding therapy
Patient has been diagnosed with depression
Patient has been diagnosed with hyperlipidemia
Number of physicians per 1,000 population in county
Percent of county residents who are employed
Percent of county population that is Caucasian
Percent of county population that is African American
Average price for intermediate length physician visit
wait longer to begin treatment after the con-
including the average delay to treatment (con-
traindication for heart disease was published in
ditional on initiating therapy). More informa-
tion on the raw delay measures is presented inTable 2, which shows the average delay timebetween the diagnosis and the first long-term use
of each COX-2 inhibitor as well as the numberof people who ultimately adopt each. We find
that patients who first adopt Celebrex tend to
deviations of the variables used in our model,
adopt more rapidly than those who first adopt
Delay between OA Diagnosis and First COX-2 Use (Number of Patients)
Average Delay for Average Delay Patients Who Do for Patients Who Not Adopt Vioxx Adopt Vioxx
Average delay for patients who do not adopt Celebrex
Average delay for patients who adopt Celebrex
Vioxx, with a delay of 163 d for the Cele-
is only one practice per media market, our
brex users, compared with a delay of 199 d
practice-level fixed effects correspond largely
for the Vioxx users. Interestingly, for all the
to media market fixed effects. Finally, we rely
attention paid to the introduction of COX-2
on the fixed effects to correct for clustering
inhibitors, and the large expenditures on promo-
(repeated observations) at the physician practice
tion on their behalf, 64% of the sample (11,741
level. The coefficient estimates are presented in
In the first model, where the COX-2 tele-
We estimate two versions of the hazard func-
vision advertising dollars for both brands are
tion presented in Equation (6). Model 1 contains
summed together, we find that television adver-
the advertising measures (as combined national
tising does have a significant effect on the delay
and local dollars spent) for Vioxx and Celebrex
in treatment. Total television spending has a pos-
together, along with the set of independent vari-
itive first derivative and negative second deriva-
ables listed above. Model 2 includes separate
tive —both significant at better than the 1%
measures for total Vioxx and Celebrex monthly
level. The parameter estimates in Table 3 are
advertising, along with the other independent
not direct measures of the net effect in terms of
variables. Thus, we will estimate the hazard rate
days of delay. Table 4 presents these net effects
for the variables of primary interest and con-verts the raw effects to days of delay inducedby a 1-unit increase in the variable of inter-
xiβ ≡ β1 · T Vi + β2 · T V 2 + β
est. When calculated at the mean of the data,
a $100,000 increase in all COX-2 advertising
4 · CV Di · T Vi · T N Mi + β5 · CV Di
during the month of diagnosis has the effect
·T Vi(1 − T NMi) + β6 · GIi + β7
of lengthening the time patients wait to begin
COX-2 therapy after being diagnosed with OA
CV Di + β · Zi + i
by about 30 d (evaluated at the mean of thedata). Note that this is in addition to average
and where TV is either the combined Vioxx and
delay periods of between 160 and 200 d delay
Celebrex national and local advertising dollars
or brand-specific national and local advertising
dollars, GI is the indicator for a gastrointestinal
vision advertising spending into separate mea-
comorbidity, CVD is the indicator for heart dis-
sures for total monthly spending on behalf of
ease comorbidities (cardiovascular disease and
Vioxx and total monthly spending on behalf
hypertension), TNM is the indicator variable
of Celebrex. We find that the results are sim-
for the post-August 2001 period (which corre-
ilar—in that spending on behalf of both brands
sponds to the publication of the Topol, Nissan,
tends to increase the delay initially and then
and Mukerjee article that first alerted the med-
lead to a decrease —again, with statistical sig-
ical profession to the increased risk for heart
nificance in excess of the 1% level. There is,
attack associated with the use of some COX-
however, a significant difference in terms of
2 inhibitors), and Z represents the remainder
where on this quadratic function the two brands
of the explanatory variables discussed above.
The vector Z also includes individual practice
In the case of Vioxx, the relationship between
fixed effects. Since in nearly all cases there
total spending and delay of therapy becomes
AFT Duration Models of Time between Diagnosis and Treatment for OA Patients
Model 1 Combined Model 2 Separated Vioxx and Celebrex Vioxx and Celebrex Variable Total Advertising Total Advertising
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising, month preceding therapy (in
0.0730 (17.300)
$100,000s)Total dollars in COX-2 advertising squared, month preceding therapy
−0.0002 (−11.91)
(in $100,000s)Total dollars in Vioxx advertising, month preceding therapy (in
0.0482 (4.17)
$100,000s)Total dollars in Vioxx advertising squared, month preceding therapy
−0.0010 (−9.12)
($100,000s)Total dollars in Celebrex advertising, month preceding therapy (in
0.0687 (14.79)
$100,000s)Total dollars in Celebrex advertising squared, month preceding
−0.0001 (−2.39)
therapy (in $100,000s)Patient has received gastrointestinal treatment
−0.0182 (−0.16)
0.0970 (0.87)
Patient has been diagnosed with heart disease
−0.3110 (−2.51)
−0.3271 (−2.63)
Interaction between gastrointestinal treatment and total COX-2
−0.0029 (−2.17)
−0.0037 (−2.69)
inhibitor advertising dollarsInteraction between heart disease and total COX-2 inhibitor advertis-
−0.0451 (−22.87)
−0.0044 (−2.16)
ing dollars during pre-TNM periodInteraction between heart disease and total COX-2 inhibitors adver-
0.0554 (32.82)
0.0132 (7.03)
tising dollars during post-TNM periodNumber of journal publications discussing COX-2 inhibitors in month
0.1709 (5.39)
−0.1664 (−4.79)
preceding therapyNumber of journal publications discussing Vioxx in month preceding
−0.0542 (−1.77)
0.1468 (4.31)
therapyNumber of journal publications discussing Celebrex in month pre-
1.2403 (26.41)
0.9796 (22.66)
1.9057 (5.42)
−0.3832 (−1.03)
2.5651 (8.18)
1.6536 (5.44)
−2.9144 (−9.41)
−2.4908 (−8.10)
0.0157 (5.87)
0.0163 (6.23)
−0.0118 (−0.16)
−0.0283 (−0.39)
Patient has been diagnosed with depression
−0.0762 (−0.90)
−0.0919 (−1.11)
0.1694 (1.85)
0.1244 (1.38)
Patient has been diagnosed with hyperlipidemia
0.1950 (2.51)
0.2036 (2.66)
−0.00003 (−5.99)
−0.00003 (−6.15)
Number of physicians per 1,000 population in county
0.0021 (1.18)
0.0034 (1.95)
0.00003 (1.52)
0.00001 (0.48)
−0.1345 (−1.39)
−0.3372 (−3.47)
Percent of county residents who are employed
−0.0871 (−5.30)
−0.0838 (−5.30)
Percent of county population that is Caucasian
−0.0159 (−1.30)
−0.0108 (−0.93)
Percent of county population that is African American
−0.2625 (−4.44)
−0.2604 (−4.53)
Average price for intermediate length physician visit
0.0686 (6.35)
0.0517 (4.85)
9.8063 (4.40)
12.7530 (5.89)
Likelihood ratio test of overall significance p value
11, 957.97 (<0.0001)
13, 164.55 (<0.0001)Note: t statistics are given in parentheses.
negative at $2.4 million per month. During
of Vioxx; thus, the marginal dollar spent for
Vioxx advertising led to a reduction in the aver-
approximately $3.5 million per month on behalf
age delay before initiating any COX-2 therapy
AFT Duration Models of Time between Diagnosis and Treatment for OA Patients. Net Marginal
Effects: Change in Days of Delay to Treatment for a 1-Unit Change in the Explanatory Variable
Model 1 Combined Model 2 Separated Vioxx and Celerex Total Vioxx and Celebrex Variable Advertising Total Advertising
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising, month preceding therapy (in
$100,000s)Total dollars in Vioxx advertising, month preceding therapy (in
$100,000s)Total dollars in Celebrex advertising, month preceding therapy (in
$100,000s)Interaction between gastrointestinal treatment and total COX-2
inhibitor advertising dollarsInteraction between heart disease and total COX-2 inhibitor adver-
tising dollars during pre-TNM periodInteraction between heart disease and total COX-2 inhibitor adver-
of approximately 14 d (Table 4). In contrast,
in that they have exhibited the sorts of gas-
the relationship between spending for Cele-
trointestinal sensitivities for which Vioxx and
brex and the delay to therapy adoption does
Celebrex were designed. Other patients have
not become negative until Pfizer would spend
hypertension and coronary disease comorbidi-
more than $34.5 million per month. During
ties that make them poor candidates for using
1999–2002, Pfizer spent $6.5 million per month
COX-2 inhibitors because these conditions have
on average—and never more than $13.8 million
been recognized as contraindications for COX-
per month. This implies that the marginal dollar
2 use since the publication of the TNM arti-
spent for Celebrex by Pfizer actually lengthens
cle. As discussed above, we estimate models
the delay in initiating any COX-2 treatment by
with interactions between total television adver-
approximately 41 d (Table 4). Thus, the positive
tising (local and national) and the GI indicator
effect of joint advertising spending on delay to
variable, the heart disease and pre-TNM indi-
adoption in the first model is driven completelyby Celebrex ads. This curious reverse associ-
cators, and the heart disease and post-TNM
ation between Celebrex television advertising
and the use of Celebrex is consistent with other
Table 3 presents the relevant parameters.
recent research we have conducted that exam-
We find strong evidence for welfare-enhancing
ined the association between television adver-
informational effects. The interaction between
tising and the rate of prescribing for Vioxx and
total COX-2 inhibitor advertising and the indi-
Celebrex at the physician practice level (Brad-
cator variable for gastrointestinal sensitivity is
negative and highly significant in both mod-
Given that we find that television adver-
els. In terms of the magnitude of the effect,
tising on behalf of the COX-2 inhibitors has
patients with GI comorbidities reduce their
some effect on the delay to use, the next ques-
wait time to adopt COX-2 inhibitor treatment
tion to address is whether this effect is welfare
by between 2 and 2.4 d for every additional
enhancing or not. As discussed above, some
$100,000 in monthly COX-2 inhibitor advertis-
patients are better candidates for COX-2 use
The effect of advertising on patients with
1. We also estimated versions of the duration of delay
heart disease comorbidities (cardiovascular dis-
for Vioxx and Celebrex separately, including spending on
ease and hypertension) depends on whether
both brands in each equation. In those models, we foundthat the general effects demonstrated in the second column
we observe the therapy being initiated prior
of Table 3 hold: Vioxx spending generally has a net effect of
to the publication of TNM or after. Prior to
reducing the delay to therapy adoption for both Vioxx andCelebrex, while Celebrex has a net effect of lengthening the
TNM, patients with cardiovascular comorbidi-
delay for both brands. Those results are available on request.
ties actually adopted COX-2 inhibitor therapy
more rapidly when exposed to increased adver-
tising. Given the information about the potential
Rural/Urban Distribution of PPRNet Practices
cardiac dangers associated with COX-2 inhibitor
use (especially Vioxx), this is contrary to whatwould improve social welfare. However, prior
to the publication of the TNM paper, this risk
Practices Patients Population
was poorly appreciated in the clinical commu-
nity. However, once the TNM paper was pub-
lished, we find a strong positive impact on delay
to therapy initiation for patients with diagnosed
heart disease when exposed to greater levels of
COX-2 inhibitor advertising. This is the direc-tion one would expect if the ads provide realinformation that assists patients and physiciansto more optimally match therapies. In fact, the
COX-2 inhibitors (either generically or focus-
post-TNM interaction effect is larger than the
ing on a specific brand) in the context of
pre-TNM interaction effect by approximately
care for patients with OA. While the measures
of clinical publication rates are uniformly sta-
Recall that we proposed relatively strong
tistically significant, there is little consistency
tests of whether DTCA for COX-2 inhibitors
in the parameter values (except for publica-
leads to welfare-enhancing or-reducing effects.
tions involving only Celebrex—which tended
If increasing DTCA is associated with reduc-
to always increase delay times). We take this
tions in the time patients who are good can-
as evidence that clinical publications are mea-
didates for the therapy wait before initiating
surably important for the prescribing patterns
treatment and is associated with increases in
of primary care clinicians in community prac-
the time patients who are poor candidates wait
tice; we cannot characterize how the effect is
before initiating treatment then the advertising
felt. This is likely because some publications
must be providing useful information to the
are favorable toward the effectiveness (and cost-
clinical matching process. In this case, DTCA
effectiveness) of COX-2 inhibitors and some are
has at least some welfare-enhancing character-
pessimistic. However, our data do not currently
istics. We find exactly this pattern in our inter-
characterize the tenor of the publication. More
actions between patients with previously treated
research on how clinical information and DTCA
GI difficulties (good candidates) and with pre-
information interact appears warranted.
viously diagnosed heart disease (poor candi-dates). In addition, the expected positive effect
from the heart disease only shows up after thefirst important clinical publication to demon-
The increased use of television advertising
strate that patients with heart disease are, in
by manufacturers of prescription pharmaceuti-
fact, at increased risk from COX-2 inhibitor use.
cal has been a controversial development over
Taken together, this evidence strongly supports
the past 5–10 yr in the United States. While the
the neoclassical view of advertising as infor-
use of such advertisement has grown dramati-cally since the early 1990s, to date, there have
mation—and throws the strong criticism that
been few studies which have empirically exam-
pharmaceutical DTCA has recently received into
ined the effect of these ads on patient care. The
primary goal of this paper was to determine what
Finally, Table 3 presents parameters which
effect local and national television advertising
test whether patients and clinicians respond to
on behalf of the two main COX-2 inhibitors had
information from the clinical literature. As dis-
on the treatment decisions that patients made in
cussed above, we included measures of gross
collaboration with their physicians. In particular,
publication rates in the month preceding ini-
the treatment decision we studied is the time
tiation of COX-2 use for papers that discuss
patients choose to wait before initiating treat-ment with either Vioxx or Celebrex. Using dataon 18,235 patients from a set of geographically
2. Note that while the absolute magnitudes of the pre-
and post-TNM interaction effects are quite different between
dispersed community-based primary care prac-
the two models, the net effects are quite similar.
tices, we have measured the determinants of the
delay between diagnosis for OA and onset of
Bradford, W. D., A. Kleit, P. Neitert, T. Mcilwain, and S.
COX-2 inhibitor therapy. To accomplish these
Ornstein. “The Effect of Direct to Consumer TelevisionAdvertising on Physician Prescribing Behavior for the
goals, we estimated a series of competing risk
Treatment of Osteoarthritis.” Health Affairs, 25(5),
duration regressions using an AFT model.
Despite the importance of our study, there
are limitations. First, without monthly data for
Cholesterol-Reducing Drugs.” Journal of Law and
pharmaceutical detailing, we were unable to
Economics,45(2, pt 2), 2002, 673–690.
account for the impact and interaction of detail-
Capozza, D., and Y. Li. “The Intensity and Timing of
ing directly. Such physician-based marketing
Investment: The Case of Land.” American Economic
remains a larger component of pharmaceuti-
Capozza, D., and Y. Li. “Optimal Land Development
cal marketing efforts than DTCA advertising.
Decisions.” Journal of Urban Economics, 51, 2002,
It is possible that DTCA and detailing efforts
were coordinated; if so, the DTCA effects mea-
Cutler, D. “The Incidence of Adverse Medical Outcomes
Under Prospective Payment.” Econometrica, 63, 1995,
sured here might have included some detail-
ing effect. Personal communication with phar-
Donohue, J., M. Cevasco, and M. Rosenthal. “A Decade
maceutical representatives, however, suggested
of Direct to Consumer Advertising of Prescription
that since both Vioxx and Celebrex were such
Drugs.” New England Journal of Medicine, 357, 2007,673–80.
important products to the manufacturers, the rep-
Dubois, R. “Pharmaceutical Promotion: Don’t Throw the
resentatives discussed these products at every
Baby Out with the Bath Water.” Health Affairs Web
opportunity. This implies that there would be
Exclusive, W3, 2003, 96–103.
little correlation between the levels of detail-
Hamilton, B. H., and V. H. Ho. “Estimating Surgi-
cal Volume-Outcome Relationships Applying Survival
ing and local or national variation in advertising,
Models: Accounting for Frailty and Hospital Fixed
which in turn would minimize the potential for
Effects.” Health Economics, 6, 1997, 383–95.
bias in the results. Second, practices also gener-
Heckman, J., and B. Singer. “A Method for Minimizing the
ally have a supply of pharmaceutical samples on
Impact of Distributional Assumptions in EconometricModels for Duration Data.” Econometrica, 52, 1984,
hand to give patients when they write a prescrip-
tion. The availability of samples may influence
Hurwitz, M., and R. Caves. “Persuasion or Information?
which product is prescribed. Again, personal
Promotion and the Shares of Brand Name and GenericPharmaceuticals.” Journal of Law and Economics, 31,
communication with physicians and pharmaceu-
tical representatives suggested that most physi-
Kalbfleisch, J., and R. Prentice. “Estimation of the Average
cians would typically have had a stock of sam-
Hazard Ratio.” Biometrika, 68, 1981, 105–112.
ples of both on hand, implying that the poten-
Keith, A. “Regulating Information About Aspirin and the
Prevention of Heart Attack.” American Economic
tial for omitted variables bias is limited. Addi-
tionally, the practice-level fixed effects included
King, C. “Marketing, Product Differentiation and Competi-
in the models capture any general tendency to
tion in the Pharmaceutical Industry.” Working Paper,MIT Department of Economics, 1996.
Kleit, A. N. “Using Advertising to Generate Information
In summary, we find that increases in tele-
and Signals for Product Quality: Lessons for Biotech-
vision advertising for Vioxx is associated with
nology in Canada from Pharmaceutical Markets in
shorter wait times between diagnosis and use.
the United States,” in Biotechnology and the Con-
On the other hand, Celebrex television adver-
sumer, edited by K. A. Mathios. Boston: Kluwer, 1998,257–75.
tising is associated with longer delays to COX-
Knight Ridder News. “Drug Maker Merck reports 5%
2 adoption. Finally, we also present evidence
Increase in Profits.” Tribune Business News, July 21,
that the effect of DTCA may tend to improve
Leffler, K. “Persuasion or Information? The Economics of
economic efficiency in that advertising tends
Prescription Drug Advertising.” Journal of Law and
to shorten the delays to adoption for patients
Economics, 24, 1981, 45–74.
who are better candidates for COX-2 use and
Masson, A., and P. Rubin. “Matching Prescription Drugs
lengthens the delay to adoption for patients who
and Consumers: The Benefits of Direct Advertis-ing.” New England Journal of Medicine, 313, 1985,
are worse candidates for the use of COX-2
McDonald, R., and D. Siegel. “The Value of Waiting to
Invest.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 1986,
REFERENCES
Merton, R. C. “An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing
Arnott, R., and F. Lewis. “The Transition of Land to Urban
Model.” Econometrica, 41, 1973, 867–87.
Use.” Journal of Political Economy, 87, 1979, 161–69.
Morrill, R., J. Cromartie, and G. Hart. “Metropolitan,
Benninga, S., M. Helmantel, and O. Sarig. “The Timing
Urban, and Rural Commuting Areas: Toward a Better
of Initial Public Offerings.” Journal of Financial Eco-
Descriptions of the United States Settlement System.”
Urban Geography, 20, 1999, 727–48.
Mukherjee, D., S. Nissen, and E. Topol. “Risk of Car-
Rubin, P. “Economics of Prescription Drug Advertising.”
diovascular Events Associated with Selective COX-2
Journal of Research in Pharmaceutical Economics,
Inhibitors.” Journal of American Medical Association,
Schumann, M. “Top 100 Megabrands: Chevrolet Leads
National Institute for Health Care Management. “Prescrip-
tion Drugs and Mass Media Advertising, 2000.”
keters Hit 2001 Potholes.” Advertising Age, 72,
Washington, DC: NIHCM Foundation, November
Telser, L. “The Theory of Supply with Application to the
“Pharmacia Has Setback for Parecoxib.” Chemical Market
Ethical Pharmaceutical Industry.” Journal of Law andEconomics, 18, 1975, 449–78.
Picone, G., R. Wilson, and S. Chou. “Analysis of Hospi-
Titman, S. “Urban Land Prices Under Uncertainty.” Ameri-
tal Length of Stay and Discharge Destination Using
can Economic Review, 75, 1985, 505–14.
Hazard Functions with Unmeasured Heterogeneity.”
“Top Brands in Network Primetime–2000.” Brandweek,
Health Economics, 12, 2003, 1021–34.
Ridder, G. “The Non-Parametric Identification of Gener-
Topol, E. “Failing the Public Health-Rofecoxib, Merck and
alized Accelerated Failure-Time Models.” Review of
the FDA.” New England Journal of Medicine, 351,
Economic Studies, 57, 1990, 167–81.
Rizzo, J. “Advertising and Competition in the Ethical
W. M., S. J., Coons, and Ginsburg, D. B.
Pharmaceutical Industry: The Case of Hypertensive
“Patient Autonomy and the Regulation of Direct-to-
Drugs.” Journal of Law and Economics, 42, 1999,
Consumer Advertising.” Clinical Therapy, 23, 2001,
Copyright of Economic Inquiry is the property of Wiley-Blackwell and its content may not be copied or
emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission.
However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.
From NOVARTIS' Speech for Elidel Product Launch, March 2002 Marketing Overview/Treatment Options Day 2 PM General Session – Focus: The Market 20 minutes After musical number "Talkin’ Trash" there is a Voice Over introduction of speaker Too bad we can’t detail the physicians with that number. This afternoon’s General Session Focus is on The Market. Elidel’s p
Compte rendu du conseil communal de Lasne du 26/01/2009 Voilà un conseil communal avec peu de points et très peu de public si ce n'est un groupe d'une quinzaine de représentants de la CSC venu pour protester contre le licenciement pour faute grave d'un de leur délégué à l'administration de Lasne. 19 conseillés sont présents 1. Approbation du procès-verbal de la séance du 15 dé